Southern African Regional Poverty Network (SARPN) SARPN thematic photo
Regional themes > Poverty reduction frameworks and critiques Last update: 2020-11-27  
leftnavspacer
Search





 Related documents

[previous] [table of contents] [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [next]

Conceptualizing RFI’s versus GFI’s - Ravi Kanbur

1. Introduction
 
We see many levels of groupings of nations on the international institutional landscape. Groups of countries that share borders often have semi-permanent cooperation agreements on immigration and customs, and institutions that implement them. Other groupings of countries come together on the basis of and to advance an ethnic, a geographical and or a cultural identity—French speaking countries, Muslim countries, Arab states, Organization of American States, etc. Others have very specific functional purposes—NATO, ASEAN, AfDB, ADB, IADB. At the highest level of aggregation, global institutions such as the U.N., the World Bank and the IMF, count on the membership of virtually every nation in the world.

The focus of this paper is on a particular type of grouping that is relatively large in terms of country coverage without being global, and one that deploys primarily financial instruments to advance its objectives. These are the Regional Financial Institutions (RFI’s)—the IADB, AfDB, ADB, EBRD, etc. A key feature of these institutions is that they have both rich and poor countries as members, the former as donors of financial resources, the latter as recipients. In other words, these institutions are intended as vehicles of development assistance. Some of the specialized UN agencies (such as UNDP) are also vehicles for transferring resources to poor countries, but they do these only through grants and do not have loan instruments. To some extent, RFI’s are smaller scale versions of fully global financial institutions (GFI’s, also known as IFI’s), the World Bank in particular. The operations of the RFI’s and GFI’s overlap in many countries, raising questions of duplication of effort and even unhealthy competition for “development business”. These tensions are immediately apparent to those with ground level experience of development assistance.

Some human activities are best performed individually. But others are enhanced when a group of individuals comes together to undertake a particular task. Underlying features of the socio-economic environment determine these characteristics. There are household economies of scale in eating from one cooking pot; exchange makes possible specialization by productivity in different activities; common defense is cheaper than individualized protection; and so on. But while grouping together can have definite scale and cost advantages, increased size of group can also make some things more difficult— for example, arriving at a decision in a potentially increasingly heterogeneous grouping. These benefits and costs of size suggest that groups will typically be of intermediate size, neither wholly individualistic nor wholly universalistic. But this still leaves an enormous range. The size will be determined by where exactly the marginal costs and benefits of size balance out, which will in turn depend on the specifics of the socioeconomic situation being discussed.

While this is true for each activity, there are likely to be similar economies (of “scope” rather than “scale”), in having the same group do more than one, related, activity. Eating together and sharing living space has economies of scope; building roads for defense and for economic transport has economies of scope; clean water and clean sanitation has economies of scope. But, eventually, diseconomies of scope will also set in, as the activities become relatively unrelated to each other. There will thus be a similar balance to be struck in this domain.

Individuals participate in a bewildering number and variety of groups, ranging from households to nation states, from single activity groupings to associations that cover a large range of activities. This is perhaps not surprising, given the range of cost and benefits patterns present in the different activities. Nation states also participate in a large number of different types of groupings, as discussed above. Taking the perspective of costs and benefits, of scale and scope, will also help us understand these groupings and to assess them. In particular, it will help us conceptualize RFI’s relative to GFI’s, especially when, as seems often to be the case, both types of institutions are engaged in the same activity.

What exactly is the rationale for the co-existence of RFI’s and GFI’s, especially in a world in which development assistance resources are increasingly scarce? If there is such a rationale, is the current mix of RFI’s and GFI’s as good as it gets, or could it be better? And if it could be better, what specific reforms are needed to move in that direction? These are the questions that are addressed in this paper.

[previous] [table of contents] [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [next]


Octoplus Information Solutions Top of page | Home | Contact SARPN | Disclaimer